Modern Derivatives Pricing – Collateral, Funding and OIS Discounting

    Posted by May 19, 2021 1:13:13 PM / Richard Fedrick

     

    The Choice of Discount Curve

    Despite what textbooks on the pricing of corporate bonds might claim, in our previous blog post, we established what interest rate derivatives discounting is not – it’s nothing to do with adjusting for counterparty risk.

    The value today of a future, possibly risky, cashflow CT is correctly computed as the credit-adjusted expectation value of the cashflow, appropriately discounted:

                                    Screen Shot 2021-05-14 at 12.15.26


    • V* represents the value in a default-free idealised world – so the cashflow is from e.g. an exchange.
    • The calculation of the XVA adjustments is a subject for another day.

    Now that we have correctly divorced discounting from the issue of pricing default risk, we can address the issue of what the PV factor in the formula above is. What rate should discounting be at?

    The answer is that we should discount at our own cost of funding.

    Here’s why: imagine a bank purchases an exchange-traded instrument that promises a future cashflow VT, for the fair market price V0. This is, by definition, a PV=0 trade.

    The cashflows on the deal, inclusive of the bank’s funding, look like this:

     Screen Shot 2021-05-14 at 12.17.29

     

    If this trade is PV = 0 (which it is), then the cashflows at t = T must net to zero, and therefore

                                                         Screen Shot 2021-05-14 at 12.18.46       

    • Or, in words, your discount rate is your funding cost.

     

    At face value, this is a rather disturbing result: it says that there is no such thing as a unique fair market price since there is no unique funding cost that applies to all market players. (We note in passing that the pre-2008 practice of discounting at LIBOR neatly solved this problem, by pretending that LIBOR was a universal proxy for the funding cost of all banks.)

    If there isn’t a unique fair price for a derivative, the consequences are profound:

    1. No concept of fair mark-to-market

     

                                                                      Screen Shot 2021-05-14 at 12.21.07

    1. Bilateral – and therefore logically zero-sum – derivative contracts are no longer zero-sum  all sorts of paradoxes

     

                                                                                 Screen Shot 2021-05-14 at 12.21.07

    1. Liquidity dries up in the interbank market, as participants cannot agree on where mid-market is and are therefore reluctant to trade

                                                                         Screen Shot 2021-05-14 at 12.21.07

     

    1. Prices worsen and liquidity dries up for the buy-side, as sell-side banks suffer from an inability to hedge in the interbank market

    This vicious cycle represents an existential threat to the derivatives market. Luckily, CSAs – and central clearing – come to the rescue.

     

    Collateral and OIS Discounting

    The widespread adoption of CSAs in the OTC world to match margining in the exchange-traded (or centrally-cleared) world, was a response to the global crisis of 2008-2009 – widely (if not entirely accurately) seen as a credit crisis.

    But collateral does something else; it addresses both the issue of counterparty risk and the issue of derivatives funding.

    To understand why consider a simple toy transaction: bank A buys a derivative, for instance, a call option, from a customer for a premium P. The call option has an expected payoff (according to Black-Scholes) of VT.

    With no CSA in place, the deal looks like this:

    Screen Shot 2021-05-14 at 12.25.27

    • And the trade is marked in the bank’s books at , i.e. discounted at the bank’s wholesale cost of funds (LIBOR ++, for most), a number that is different for every bank.

     

    With a CSA in place, the picture is different:

    Screen Shot 2021-05-14 at 12.25.51

     

    Now there is no external wholesale funding required because the premium is auto-funded by the transfer of collateral. And therefore, the effective cost of funding is the interest payable on the collateral account, which is OIS, and so OIS is the right curve for discounting.

     

    A Few Points are Worth Emphasising

    This argument, that any funding/reinvestment requirements will be covered by collateral transfers, doesn’t just hold for option premiums as above but is generally true for any derivatives position on a risk-neutral expectation value basis.

    If you need to convince yourself that this is true, just think about how the market defines/computes a forward price.

     – The argument above does not just hold at trade level – collateral is computed on a netted portfolio basis, so OIS discounting applies to all instruments within the portfolio governed by the same CSA

     – We have (almost) solved the ‘uniqueness’ problem we previously discussed – because all CSAs are (at least to first-order) the same; they all specify that interest is payable at the market’s ‘official’ overnight RFR

     – And even when the CSA has anomalous terms such as zero-strike EURIBOR floors, it is convenient to use the same formalism and deal with the anomalies as standalone adjustments (another XVA)

     

    Summary and Conclusions

    ‘Standard’ CSAs (ISDA’s ‘SCSA’) specify interest is payable on posted cash collateral at OIS, and therefore that is the right curve to use for valuing a cash-collateralised derivatives portfolio. This is what has naturally become known as ‘OIS discounting’.

    The calculation of the OIS discount curve – i.e. DF(t) – from the par OIS curve is a straightforward calibration exercise, popularly known as ‘bootstrapping’. I imagine this is familiar to most readers, but if not, you should come to the next running of LFS’s Interest Rate Derivatives and Swaps, where we do lots of bootstrapping.

    This is all good, but problems remain.

    What if:

    • The CSA allows collateral to be posted in cash, but in another currency?
    • The CSA allows collateral to be posted in the right currency, but in government bonds?
    • Or even worse, the CSA allows multiple choices of the collateral format?

    In part three of this series, we will address these questions and establish what is meant by ‘CSA discounting’.

     

    Related Courses

    Interest Rate Derivatives and Swaps
    Interest Rate Derivatives 2: Options
    Interest Rate Derivatives 3: Structuring
    •  

    Topics: Modern Derivatives Pricing, OIS Discounting

    Written by Richard Fedrick

    Richard specialises interest rate and FX, derivatives, exotics, structured products and risk management. He started his career at Morgan Stanley, and spent three years as a rates and FX structurer before moving to Deutsche Bank in London, where he joined a newly-formed team designing and selling structured products across Europe. In 1993 Richard joined General Re Financial Products, an AAA-rated derivatives boutique that rapidly became established as one of the world’s leading derivatives trading operations. At GRFP, Richard ran the structuring desk, before becoming Managing Director and global co-head of structuring and sales. He then joined Dresdner Kleinwort Wasserstein in 2002 before moving into executive education in 2004. Richard has a 1st Class degree in Physics from St John’s College, University of Oxford.

    Recent Posts

    Ask Teacher
    Subscribe
    Subscribe
    Ask the Teacher

    Follow Us

    Contact Us

    Recent Posts

    Monetising Convexity (Q&A from the Webinar)

    1. Is it fair to say that options actually have two types of convexity: one due to the payoff structure, working along the underlying’s price..

    Mar 13, 2024 4:38:11 PM / by Richard Fedrick

    Fixed Income Attribution – Towards a Generic Model? (Part 2)

    This article was first published in the Journal of Performance Measurement Volume 27-4, Summer 2023

    Jan 19, 2024 4:46:51 PM / by Paul Giles